Search This Blog

Friday, December 31, 2021

Left with a Smoky Rental? Here’s How to Get Rid of Cigarette Smell

 Maybe you never thought to ask your tenants if they were smokers. Maybe you could tell that they smoked cigarettes but assumed they would be courteous enough to do it outdoors. Whatever happened, your rental now reeks of cigarette smoke, even months after the tenants have moved out. The smell is pervasive and it’s hard to tell what area(s) you should target first.

The odor infecting your rental is known as thirdhand smoke—the residual contamination left behind from use of tobacco products like cigarettes and cigars. The smell/presence of thirdhand smoke isn’t merely unpleasant, it’s harmful to the health of all future residents.

Thirdhand smoke indicates the presence of tobacco toxins, which stick to ceilings and walls and gets absorbed by carpets, drapes, and other surfaces. Thirdhand smoke is especially harmful to those with asthma or allergies, contributing to asthma attacks and allergic reactions.

So how do you get rid of that cigarette smell?

Form a plan of attack and take it one step at a time.

Air out your rental.

To begin with, you need to air out your rental unit. Open all of the windows and blinds (or curtains). Then use fans on opposite sides of the rental property, one facing out and one facing in, to push out stale air and draw in fresh air. Turn on any ceiling fans you may have available to help out.

You might also consider purchasing a cigarette smoke air purifier to help expedite the odor removal process. If any of your property’s rooms feel particularly damp, a dehumidifier will aid in extracting any odors trapped in the moisture. Having your air ducts professionally cleaned will also be a major help in getting your rental property a smoke-free scent.

Start at the top.

Wash the ceilings with the cleaner of your choice. Smooth ceilings can be wiped down with a washcloth while popcorn ceilings can be misted with a spray bottle of cleaning solution. Be sure to sanitize the tops of the ceiling fans as well.

From the windows to the walls.

Thoroughly clean all of the windows, window coverings (blinds, curtains, etc.), and walls next. If the smell lingers for a while after cleaning your windows and walls, consider replacing your window coverings and repainting your walls and ceiling.

Deodorize carpets.

An effective way to get the smoke smell out of your carpets and rugs is to sprinkle baking soda over the affected areas. Let the baking soda sit for 30 minutes to one hour before vacuuming. If the cigarette odor persists, consider renting a carpet cleaning machine, hiring professional carpet cleaners, or replacing your carpeting altogether.

Mop the floors.

Once you get your carpeting squared away, tackle the hardwoods and tile. Sweep the flooring before you mop the area with your choice of disinfectant. Regularly swapping out the water in the bucket for freshness while you’re mopping will ensure that you aren’t simply spreading the thirdhand smoke around.

Clean the counters and cabinets.

Cigarette smell even gets trapped on counters as well as the interior and exterior of cabinets! Wipe down all cabinets and counters with cleaning solution. Then, leave the cabinets and drawers open to air out and dry.

If the smoke odor lingers after you’ve cleaned everything, try keeping bowls of dry coffee grounds or white vinegar in the offending cabinets or drawers for a few days to get rid of the cigarette smell.

As offensive as strong cigarette odors can be, everything is not lost if your rental property currently has a lingering smoke smell. To prevent this predicament from happening again, consider advertising your rental property as a smoke-free unit or building in the future. Think about installing a cigarette smoke detector as well. According to a 2013 survey, smoking in the home can reduce property resale value by nearly 30 percent.

https://www.american-apartment-owners-association.org/property-management/left-with-a-smoky-rental-here-s-how-to-get-rid-of-cigarette-smell/

Sunday, December 26, 2021

City communities should have right to say no to legal pot before Dec. 31 deadline

 As the end of 2021 approaches, we see the usual focus on New Year’s resolutions. But one of the most important, and little-noticed, decisions for municipalities across New York must be made this year, not next or any time in the future: whether to exercise the right to opt out of permitting marijuana dispensaries and consumption sites, as permitted by state cannabis legalization.

With little fanfare, a great pot divide is opening between cities and suburbs — and disadvantaged urban neighborhoods, long suffering from drug use, look again to be the losers, denied even the choice the more affluent are exercising.

According to the Rockefeller Institute of Government’s frequently updated Marijuana Opt-Out Tracker, 588 of 1,518 municipalities have resisted the blandishments of new tax revenues and just said no to marijuana retailers, while 670 have turned down consumption sites — what the Dutch euphemistically call “coffee shops.”

Hundreds of towns have yet to decide. In New Jersey, where the opt-out deadline passed in August, 71 percent of local governments decided to keep pot out.

It’s revealing to review who’s giving thumbs up to weed and who’s resisting its temptation. Cities large and small — New York, White Plains, Schenectady, Mount Vernon, Peekskill, Yonkers — have opted in. But adjoining suburbs are opting out in droves: Scarsdale, Pelham and Bronxville have. No municipality in Nassau County — not one — has opted in.

There’s money involved. Localities will receive 4 percent of the 9 percent state excise tax — and cities under budget pressure may see a “pot” of gold.

a jar of medical marijuana sits on the counter at a dispensary in Sherwood, Ore.
A great pot divide is opening between cities and suburbs.
AP Photo/Gillian Flaccus, File

Persons of good faith can disagree about whether cannabis should be legal — and whether it’s a good idea for adults to inhale. Recent research findings about the drug’s effects on brain development in adolescents and young adults are, however, sobering. The surgeon general warned last year that “until and unless more is known about the long-term impact, the safest choice for pregnant women and adolescents is not to use marijuana.”

The point is that well-off suburbs are choosing to go slow — and it’s a choice they can make. In contrast, city neighborhoods — many as residential in character as their suburban counterparts — don’t get a choice. They’re opted-in by, for instance, the New York City Council.

On the Queens-Nassau line, pot shops could spring up in Bayside and Jamaica but won’t be seen in Great Neck. Are we sure that central Harlem residents — already protesting so-called safe-injection sites for hard-drug users — want to see a proliferation of pot retailers tempting their kids?

This is a form of vote suppression, if you will: Every New York City community board should have as much right as Hempstead or New Castle to say no to cannabis outlets. The risk to disadvantaged, minority neighborhoods — disproportionately found within big-city boundaries — is evident.

The inside of the Columbia Care medical marijuana dispensary is seen in New York January 7, 2016.
Hundreds of New York localities have not taken a position on pot sales.
REUTERS/Shannon Stapleton/File Photo

There is much to be concerned about what Scott Gottlieb, former Food and Drug Administration commissioner, has called a “natural experiment” in making widely available cannabis said to be far more potent than its 1960s version — especially when more than 100,000 Americans have died of drug overdoses in the last year. No, pot is not the same as fentanyl (though some versions are laced with it). But the combination of thrill-seeking, alienation and self-medication that can drive drug use is common to both.

State governments, searching for yet more sin tax revenues, acquiesce in legalization and send a signal of harmlessness, despite the fact that the FDA reports it “has not approved a marketing application for cannabis for the treatment of any disease or condition.”

Hundreds of New York localities — including Albany and Buffalo — have not taken a position on pot sales and face the looming New Year’s Eve deadline. The law permits them to opt in at any time. This is their only chance to just say no. Let’s hope city councils and town boards listen closely to their communities.

Howard Husock is a senior fellow in domestic-policy studies at the American Enterprise Institute. 

https://nypost.com/2021/12/26/city-communities-should-be-able-to-say-no-to-legal-pot-before-dec-31/

China central bank says to promote healthy development of property market

 China's central bank has vowed to promote healthy development of the country's real estate market, saying it will safeguard the legal rights of home buyers and better satisfy their reasonable living needs.

The statement from the People's Bank of China (PBOC), made following its fourth-quarter monetary policy committee meeting on Saturday, is the latest sign that Chinese regulators are marginally easing curbs on the property sector to prevent a hard-landing.

Echoing China's annual Central Economic Work Conference held in early December, the PBOC said it will prioritize economic stability, amid an increasingly severe external environment and the unrelenting global pandemic.

"The PBOC...turned more cautious on its growth outlook, indicated an intention to use broad and targeted policy tools to support the real economy in a more pro-active manner, and on the margin eased its tone on the property sector," said analysts at Goldman Sachs in a note on Sunday.

"We expect the central bank to inject more long-term liquidity via RRR cuts and various lending facilities, on-budget fiscal expenditures to be more supportive to growth compared with 2021, and local governments to ease property policies at local levels."

The PBOC said it will keep its monetary policy flexible and appropriate, and liquidity reasonably ample. It will strengthen support to the real economy, with a bias toward small companies.

The central bank reiterated that it will deepen reforms of the forex market and increase the flexibility of the yuan's exchange rate while guiding companies and financial institutions to be "risk neutral."

https://www.marketscreener.com/quote/stock/BANK-OF-CHINA-LIMITED-1412661/news/China-c-bank-says-to-promote-healthy-development-of-property-market-37414030/

On urbanization, the future of small towns, and "Yes In My Back Yard"

 Harvard University's Edward Glaeser, considered by many to be the foremost economist of cities and of the forces influencing their development, is known for defending the role of cities as places where businesses and residents can exploit the benefits of social and economic interactions.

As a teenager, he lived on the Upper East Side of New York during the Bonfire of the Vanities era. His eventual specialization in urban economics was influenced, he says, by his growing up in the city during its times of crisis and recovery. "My childhood was shaped by the arc of New York City during the '70s and '80s, first as a period of startling decline as crime rates exploded and the city teetered on the brink of bankruptcy, and then its remarkable comeback," he remembers. "And it was hard as a child not to wonder at this amazing variety of things that were happening in the city."

Glaeser was promoted to chair of Harvard's economics department in July. He has authored scores of journal articles and book chapters and is a member of the editorial board of five journals of urban or regional economics. He is the author or editor of 12 books, many of them on the economics of cities or on housing policy. His most recent, Survival of the City: Living and Thriving in an Age of Isolation, written with Harvard colleague David Cutler, was published in September.

David A. Price interviewed Glaeser by phone in September 2021.


EF: In your new book, Survival of the City, you argue that technological changes in the postwar period were mostly "centrifugal," leading people and companies to move away from urban cores, while technological changes in the 21st century have been "centripetal," leading to more concentration in urban cores. Please explain.

Glaeser: I see urban growth as almost uniformly a dance between technologies that pull us together and ones that push us apart.

Technologies of the 19th century, like the skyscraper — which is really the combination of a steel frame and an elevator — the streetcar, the steam engine, all of these things enabled the growth of 19th century cities. They brought people together. This was a centripetal age.

In the mid-20th century, we had technologies that were major jumps forward in transportation cost. In transportation technology, like the car, and in technology for transporting ideas and entertainment — television and radio — these were centrifugal forces that basically flattened the Earth and made it easier to live in far-flung suburbs or even rural areas.

Those centrifugal technologies were the backdrop for New York's decline during the 1970s. They were the backdrop for the exodus of people from dense cities that had been built around streetcars and subways and to suburbs that were built around the car.

But then in the late 20th century and early 21st century, the tides turned again. And it was somewhat surprising. With this shift came a vision in which the rise in these forms of information technology would lead the knowledge workers that still existed in cities to follow the path of industrial workers and essentially deurbanize. Knowledge workers would work remotely from electronic cottages.

But for most of the last 40 years, that hasn't been correct at all. That hasn't been happening in cities. We've started to see the electronic cottages become a force during the pandemic, and suburbanization has continued, but downtowns are vastly stronger than they were in the 1980s. And I think the primary reason is that globalization and new technologies have radically increased the returns to being smart, and we are a social species that gets smart by being around other smart people. That's why people are willing to pay so much to be in the heart of Silicon Valley and why they're willing to pay so much for downtown real estate in Chicago or New York or London.

EF: What does the future of small towns look like after the pandemic?

Glaeser: I think that's going to be a tale of two towns. If you are a small town like a college town, a place with high levels of amenities and beautiful scenery where rich people want to go, I think that the combination of the ability to do work remotely and perhaps some enduring pandemic fears means that you are as strong as you've ever been, if not more so. These places are poised to benefit.

Take your Silicon Valley startup with 15 smart, hungry young people. Do we truly think in five years these people are just going to be Zooming it in from their suburban bedrooms? That sounds totally implausible to me. That sounds like a totally different work model that will lack all the energy and high quality in-person connections you get from being in the same room as one another.

But on the other hand, are these 15 people going to decide, "Well we all love skiing, we're tired of paying Silicon Valley prices, should we relocate to Vail?" Or say, "We don't want to pay taxes, let's relocate to Austin." Or, "We want better surfing, let's relocate to Honolulu." That feels entirely plausible to me. The technology supports the mobility en masse of these groups to some different area. Places they're most likely to relocate to are high-amenity places that will appeal to them along one of these dimensions.

These would be probably the best index right now of whether or not a place is likely to benefit: Among small towns, is it a skilled place already? Prior to COVID-19, did it do a good job of attracting large numbers of college graduates or people who had advanced degrees?

On the other hand, if you're talking about small towns in relatively low-amenity places, places that are low density, farmland, low levels of education, these places have been declining for decades, and I see little reason why the decline would be reversed anytime soon.

EF: Place-based policies — that is, policies aimed at improving specific areas — are often criticized by economists. You've argued that they may be justified for some areas of the American heartland where men have low labor force participation. Why is that?

Glaeser: I still maintain my traditional aversion to place-based policies. I have not completely gone away from it.

But I do think that the persistence of prime-age male joblessness is worrisome. If you look at the relationship in the Public Use Microdata Areas between joblessness in 2010 and joblessness in 1980, the correlation is over 80 percent. We have an enduring level of local economic dysfunction. I don't think that this makes the case for large-scale redistribution in these areas. I think there are many good reasons for being wary of that, but at the same time, I think it's necessary to think about policies that are more place-specific.

Take housing. You really don't need to subsidize the production of low-income housing in most of Texas, because they have an unfettered market that does a great job of providing lots of low-cost housing to middle-income residents. If you have Detroit, you don't want to produce more low-cost housing, because they've got an abundance of low-cost housing there. But on the other hand, there's probably a good case for doing something about low-cost housing in San Francisco or New York or Boston.

That suggests to me, at least, that you want policies like the low-income housing tax credit that subsidizes new housing construction. You want that to be spatially limited. You want it to go in areas where there's a genuine dearth of low-income housing. At the same time, you could have more housing vouchers in the areas where housing supply is elastic. You can have the right policy for the right place, which is something that America has traditionally found very difficult to do. But it's just basic economics.

Likewise, if you're going to have a large-scale employment subsidy, it makes more sense to put that subsidy into places where it will actually encourage the most employment. That's much more likely in places that start with high levels of nonemployment, like the eastern heartland.

Now, my own preference is that you make it feel relatively budget neutral and figure out other things to deliver more of to other areas. But I think we have to realize that the eastern heartland, particularly, has very specific circumstances that need distinct policies. So, when we're discussing a $15 national minimum wage, that's fine in Seattle; we've had a whole bunch of papers on this over the past five or six years that show it won't hurt employment much. If you have a $15 minimum wage in West Virginia, you're risking much more of an increased joblessness problem there because you're starting at a very different place.

"I think we have to realize that the eastern heartland, particularly, has very specific circumstances that need distinct policies. So, when we're discussing a $15 national minimum wage, that's fine in Seattle; we've had a whole bunch of papers on this over the past five or six years that show it won't hurt employment much. If you have a $15 minimum wage in West Virginia, you're risking much more of an increased joblessness problem there."

 

EF: What is your view of opportunity zones as a policy in this regard?

Glaeser: We have a paper on this that does try and compare them with truly comparable areas. We're focused mainly on the effect on housing prices, which we thought would be one measure of whether things are getting better in the area. We find almost no effect from these zones on prices.

I think in general that the needs of these places are really about human capital problems rather than a lack of entrepreneurship. But the opportunity zone structures are very oriented toward more investment in physical capital, including housing and apartments and such, which does not particularly seem like the right thing to do for these disadvantaged areas. When I think about what I would like to see in a zone, it's much more focused on the human capital than the physical side.

EF: Why have major investing institutions recently started buying single-family homes in large numbers?

Glaeser: Traditionally, single-family homes were overwhelmingly owner-occupied in the U.S. More than 85 percent, I think, of homes were owner-occupied. The usual view of the housing economics community was that the agency problems involved in renting them out were huge. There are estimates that suggest that renting out for a year involves a 1 percent decline in the value of the house, or something like that, because the renter just doesn't treat it properly.

By contrast, traditionally more than 85 percent of multi-family housing was rented, at least once you get to over five stories. It's much easier to manage a multi-unit building when you have one owner. One roof, one owner, because otherwise you've got the problems of coordination of the condo association or the co-op board, which can be more fractious.

So those were the things, I think, that were responsible for tying ownership type and structure type so closely together. We are starting to see that break down, which is quite interesting. I don't know if these buyers have fully internalized their difficulties with the maintenance that goes into rental houses as a long-run issue. Or if technology has changed in such a way that they think that they can actually solve that agency problem and that they can figure out ways to deal with the maintenance costs in some efficient fashion.

I'm happy to see an emergence of a healthy rental market in single-family detached housing, but I'm keenly aware of the limitations and difficulties of doing that. So, we'll have to see how this plays out. I can't help thinking some part of it just has to be that investors are simply searching for new investment products.

EF: In Survival of the City, you write about development restrictions as favoring insiders, by which you mean homeowners. Homeowners might say, "Don't we want local government to be responsive to local interests?" Is this a good thing as well as a bad thing?

Glaeser: I certainly don't want local government to be nonresponsive to local interests. The problem is that local majorities are not necessarily going to take into account everyone. They won't necessarily take into account minorities, and they certainly won't take into account people who are not in the locality right now.

As always in the case of democracy, we want something that empowers the majority, but also slightly restrains it in different ways. We want the Bill of Rights as well as the grants of power in the Constitution. And in the case of localities, I think that the idea of placing some restriction on what localities can do is quite reasonable to me.

For example, in the area of housing, you have Massachusetts Chapter 40B, which basically enables developers to work around local zoning if the locality has almost no affordable housing and if the developer is providing some low-cost units to buyers. They're able to take advantage of the state process rather than the local process for getting approval. So, you're not getting rid of all local power over zoning. But if your local power means that you produce nothing that's affordable, we're going to maintain a way for the builders of affordable housing to basically bypass you. That sort of hybrid model seems like a good one to me.

The new California law, SB 9, on speedy permitting of two-unit buildings will also be a state restriction on local power. This was the first time in many years we've had a victory for the "Yes In My Back Yard" movement — the YIMBYs. It may be a small victory, but you know, when I started thinking about this stuff in 2001, there was nothing. There was no popular movement of any form to reduce the local straitjacket on building.

EF: The famous 1961 book by Jane Jacobs, The Death and Life of Great American Cities, has been influential over the years in people's thinking about urban development. What was she right about, and what was she wrong about?

Glaeser: It's a wonderful, wonderful book. It's so wise in its understanding of urban neighborhoods and the street life and the ability of neighborhoods to just work and the dangers of trying to engage in planning. All of that stuff is fantastic.

Where she kind of screws up is when she gets into a discussion of how cities need old buildings. It's not that she's totally wrong, not at all. It's great for cities to have some form of inexpensive space. And in most cities, that inexpensive space comes from older buildings that have not yet been upgraded. The way that affordability is supposed to work is that you build new buildings, which are usually not that cheap, and that reduces the pressure to gentrify old buildings. So that's where affordability comes from.

But that led her to the policy view that you actually want to prevent tearing down old buildings and replacing them with new buildings. Now, if the two buildings are exactly the same size, I agree that replacing the old building with the new building will not promote affordability.

But that's not typically what developers want to do. Typically, they want to take a short building and replace it with a tall building. And if you stop that process, as she was so instrumental in doing in the Greenwich Village historic preservation district — which was part of a great popular wave of opposition to rebuilding New York — you aren't promoting affordability, you are freezing a neighborhood in amber. In the case of Greenwich Village, you have created a situation in which townhouses start, at least before the pandemic, at over $7 million. That's no recipe for affordable urban space that scrappy startups and young families can buy, which is how she was thinking about it.

That was, I think, the thing that she got most wrong. She was right in many of her ground-level observations, but economics is really helpful for thinking through the long-run implications of a policy intervention.

"If you stop that process, as [Jane Jacobs] was so instrumental in doing in the Greenwich Village historic preservation district, you aren't promoting affordability, you are freezing a neighborhood in amber. That's no recipe for affordable urban space that scrappy startups and young families can buy, which is how she was thinking about it."

 

EF: You wrote in your book that the 1970s were a catastrophic decade for much of urban America. Why were the 1970s catastrophic for cities?

Glaeser: It's that combination of the centrifugal technologies — the fact that container ships and highways made it easy for factories to relocate to places where land and labor were cheaper, and highways made it possible for wealthier urbanites to leave for suburbs.

That process collided with the dreams of progressive mayors, like New York's John Lindsay or Detroit's Jerome Cavanagh, who were trying to fix the very visible woes of cities. What that meant was that just at the time cities were asking businesses to pay more, asking the rich to pay more, it was becoming easier for the rich and for businesses to get out. And that's exactly what happened.

On top of that, of course, there was an inability to deal with the crime problem. That's something that I worry about today. There is a totally understandable desire to try and deal with the terrible inequities of urban life. There's a totally understandable desire to want to do something about policing and the experience that many people have with the police. But if the changes that occur either end up targeting the taxpaying members of the urban community or end up leading to a significant deterioration in the quality of life — for example, with an increase in crime rates — that risks replaying the 1970s.

One of the reasons why I wrote the book was to emphasize that we had paths to try to reduce those inequities and could make those cities not just more functional but more humane. But at the same time, cities have to do that in a way that respects the need to continue to attract the taxpayers who ultimately fund things.

EF: You wrote that court-ordered school busing and the reaction to it played a role. In what way?

Glaeser: The way that busing got implemented was the court requirement getting rid of segregation in cities. But there was also a court ruling saying that you could not force desegregation across city boundaries.

For example, the Supreme Court decision in Milliken v. Bradley in 1974 said essentially that federal courts could not require desegregation across school districts. What that meant was that if you wanted to avoid busing, either for racist reasons or for some other reasons, you could get that only by leaving the school districts — by leaving the city. And so, for thousands and thousands of parents, that's when they moved, sometimes just outside the city's school district.

If you had metropolitan-area-level desegregation efforts, that would not have created the same incentive. Or if you had something that was more like a charter school system or like a voucher school system. Anything that breaks the link between where you live and where you go to school would've been less harmful for cities. But as it was, this was yet another huge incentive for parents to get out. And a harmful one.

And ex post, if you look at the Opportunity Atlas data created by my colleague Raj Chetty and his co-authors, there was a clear and discernable break in upward mobility at the border of central city school districts across America. Opportunity jumps up if you're just outside the central city school districts as opposed to just inside it. This is a cohort that was born between 1978 and 1983, and you can see it in their adult earnings. They are also significantly less likely to be incarcerated as an adult.

EF: Winston Churchill said in 1943, "We shape our buildings and afterwards our buildings shape us." Was he right? And if he was, what are the trade-offs in regulating architecture?

Glaeser: Yes, he was right. It's one of the greatest of all lines about architecture, absolutely.

The regulation of architecture is probably the most straightforward element of this in some sense. I have a paper with Nikhil Naik, who is a computer scientist, where we look at the connection between the appearance of your neighbor's home and your housing value. We find significant effects, and the effects are much stronger if you are on the same street as opposed to being, say, half a block away outside of the sightline. People value having nicer homes to look at, and that creates at least some scope for benefits from regulating architecture.

On the other hand, I believe people are willing to pay for architecture. Moreover, as the son of an architectural historian, I continue to be skeptical about the abilities of states to regulate architecture well. [Glaeser's father, Ludwig Glaeser, was a curator in architecture and design at the Museum of Modern Art.]

There are special cases. The vista of a city or the elegance or the magic of, for example, some streets of Barcelona or the Place des Vosges in Paris — these are magical urban spaces. And certainly, I am OK with protecting those pieces of architecture that are widely accepted to be part of the patrimony of the city.

But when it comes to building new buildings, we have to be aware that very rarely does great architecture happen by committee. And very rarely will a zoning board be the best judge of what design is going to create joy in people for decades to come. It doesn't take much to convince me that there's a market failure in many cases, that cities are chock full of externalities, but saying that the government is actually going to make it better is a much heavier lift. I'm not sure it's here in this case.

In terms of how buildings shape us, I certainly believe that the structure of our offices shapes who we interact with and end up shaping our lives. There is evidence to show that people who are physically proximate to each other end up influencing each other. I think about, say, Bruce Sacerdote's work at Dartmouth on randomized roommates. There's an older MIT study that suggests that if you are randomly put closer to each other, you are more likely to form friendships. Plenty of evidence suggests that human proximity shapes interactions. None of this is surprising, but it is powerful and reminds us that physical proximity continues to be highly important.

For those younger economists who are reading this, I think that would be a great place to think about using, say, randomized controlled trials or something else to figure out to what extent Churchill is correct when it comes to day-to-day office life and street life and how our buildings are shaping us.

Edward Glaeser

Present Position

Fred and Eleanor Glimp Professor of Economics and Department Chair, Harvard University

Selected Additional Affiliations

Director, Urban Economics Working Group, National Bureau of Economic Research
Editorial Board Member, Journal of Urban Economics
Board Member, Social Science Research Council
Fellow, Econometrics Society
Member, American Academy of Arts and Sciences

Education

Ph.D. (1992), University of Chicago; A.B. (1988), Princeton University


https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/econ_focus/2021/q4_interview

Saturday, December 25, 2021

NYC hotels face latest COVID challenge

 Some 100 city hotels were forced to shut their doors due to the pandemic, and those that survived are now pushing to lower crushing property taxes, according to an industry group.

Hotels were starting to bounce back in early December, as COVID-era travel restrictions began to lift, but the much-needed recovery hit a brick wall when the Omicron variant emerged and COVID cases in New York surged.

Now hotels already fighting to stay afloat with crippled vacancy rates are contending with Big Apple property taxes that have soared 100% since 2008 and are double those of other major cities, one study found.

“The industry was really hammered and it’s not going to be pleasant for the first quarter” because of increasing Omicron-fueled COVID cases, said Vijay Dandapani, the president of the Hotel Association of New York City, adding “at the same time we are being punitively taxed.”

Hotels are paying city property taxes that eat up 9.4% of their revenues, according to a new report by global hotel consultants HVS, compiled for the association.

That’s twice what the industry needs to stay afloat and nearly double the 4.5% taxes major U.S. cities like Washington and Los Angeles levy on their hotels, the study found. Hotels in Atlanta pay just 2.29% of their revenue.

Of the surge in hotel property taxes, 25 to 30% of the increase has come under the de Blasio administration.

Vijay Dandapani, President & CEO at Hotel Association of New York City
Vijay Dandapani, president & CEO at Hotel Association of New York City, said “it’s not going to be pleasant for the first quarter.”
Monica Schipper/Getty Images for Hotel Association of New York City (HANYC)

And the wave of hotel closures isn’t finished: another half dozen have reportedly filed for bankruptcy, such as The Williamsburg, or in some cases are being foreclosed on, like the Standard High Line.

Other city costs also trend higher. Furniture replacement is 44.3% of Big Apple hotel budgets, but just 36.5% elsewhere.

And under a new city law, if large hotels with 100 rooms or more that had been shut because of the pandemic did not open by Nov. 1, owners are forced to make hefty payments to employees of $500 per week for 30 weeks, even if they’d already given their workers severance.

“Our industry got slammed,” said Dandipani. “We lost 85% of revenue for 2020 and now we are at 50% of occupancy compared to 2019.”

Williamsburg Hotel
The Williamsburg Hotel has reportedly filed for bankruptcy.
Ed Reeve/View Pictures/Universal Images Group via Getty Images

Before the pandemic, from January through October of 2019, hotels had a robust 86% occupancy and revenue per room, known as RevPar, of $213.

The lockdowns brought occupancy through Oct. 31, 2020 plunging to a mere 49%, and RevPar of just $76.

In 2021, occupancy through October was 57% with RevPar at $108, and those that reopened for November as international travel resumed saw even better numbers, with occupancy jumping to 72% and RevPar hitting $185.

This month had been a bright spot, with 81% occupancy through Dec. 11 and RevPar of $274 — until COVID-19 cases began increasing.

“December is decent but it’s a long way ‘til normalcy,” Dandipani observed.

A view of of the Standard Hotel at the High Line with rooms lit in the shape of a heart in solidarity because of the COVID-19 pandemic on April 12, 2020 in New York City,
The Standard Hotel at the High Line is being foreclosed on.
Roy Rochlin/Getty Images

City statutes require hotel property taxes to be based on income and expenses, but Dandipani complained the city’s Department of Finance “has its own formula … that bears little resemblance to the decline in revenue.”

Although revenue declined by more than 65% in 2020, Dandipani said, the billable taxes for 2020/2021 fell by just 21%.

“This resulted in tax bills that were punitive,” Dandipani said.

During fiscal years 2019 and 2020, 1,000 hotels forked over $1.05 billion in property taxes to the city and were billed $841 million in property taxes for the fiscal year through June 2022, he said. 

At the end of June 2020, 61 hotels owed $7.1 million in property taxes, compared to 56 hotels that owed $4 million in 2019. Finance did not provide the 2021 delinquency data.

https://nypost.com/2021/12/25/nyc-hotels-face-latest-covid-challenge/

Thursday, December 23, 2021

Inside ‘Antiques Roadshow’ appraiser Nicholas Lowry’s eclectic NYC home

Nicholas Lowry, the 53-year-old president of Swann Auction Galleries and a longtime appraiser of PBS’ “Antiques Roadshow,” describes his Manhattan apartment as a “wunderkammer,” or a cabinet of curiosities. 

He’s stuffed the one-bedroom rental with items that keep him happy — such as some 50 busts of figures from Beethoven to Elvis and roughly 60 plants (including three trees) that front a 15-foot window — and he hopes they also charm anyone who visits.

“A lot of people [say], ‘Oh my God, this is going to take me hours to go through, there’s so much to see,’ ” the Manhattan native told The Post. “And I’m happy to let people do that when they come over.” 

Lowry has lived in this stately apartment near Union Square — whose great room features wood paneling and gargoyles under a 27-foot beamed cathedral ceiling — for seven years, and he intends to keep filling the space with curios.

“It really is the outer manifestation of my inner mind,” he said. “I’m a little ADD, I’m a little bit of a hoarder and I like things around me. The way I dress is very colorful and eclectic, and I guess that’s the way I live … it makes me comfortable.”

A suit of armor.
Lowry’s collection includes a joust-worthy suit of armor.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

Lowry recently opened his door to Homeworthy, a real estate- and interior design-focused media company that profiles big personalities and the grand homes they live in, which got a first-hand peek of his collection of, well, everything.

A couch with a poop emoji pillow.
A couch wouldn’t be fit for the home without a poop emoji pillow.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

In the October-shot video, Lowry also shows off a gumball machine filled with matchbooks, a vintage newspaper/magazine rack now used as a bar, even a reproduction of a suit of armor whose helmet is topped with a crown of pink flowers.

A plant inside the home.
One of some five dozen plants inside the well-landscaped home.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

What’s more, Lowry also keeps a stock of vintage posters — particularly a collection of hangings from his father’s native Czechoslovakia — many of which he can’t hang. They number in the hundreds, but it isn’t wall space that prevents him from displaying them.

The great room’s walls come adorned with a well-preserved golden brocade fabric, which he neither wants to cover nor destroy — so he hung some of them in a hallway leading to his bedroom. One is a 1930s advertisement for Czech motorcycle manufacturer JAWA, which shows a man cruising on a lipstick-red ride.

Busts of Chopin and ben Franklin.
Chopin and Ben Franklin count among the home’s collection of busts.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

But it’s another poster that has his heart.

Perched on the mantel over his great room fireplace, there’s a framed illustration of Consul, the performing chimpanzee who was regarded as the smartest monkey in the world, who’s dressed in a patterned suit and riding a bicycle.

A mantle with Consul the monkey framed.
Lowry and Consul the chimp (seen here framed) have a similar fashion sense.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

“It speaks to me on so many levels,” Lowry told The Post of this piece. “It speaks to my poster collecting, it speaks to my interest and knowledge of history, and it speaks to fashion — because basically that monkey is dressed the way I dress.”

In his kitchen, another prized poster. A riff on a 1960s ad campaign for Levy’s Jewish Rye Bread, which famously showed people of various ethnicities eating sandwiches under text saying, “You don’t need to be Jewish to love Levy’s,” Lowry’s frame shows a chimp eating a piece of bread. “You don’t have to be human to love Levy’s,” it reads.

An old-timey phonograph and telescope.
Lowry has an old-timey phonograph and telescope.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

“Having been in the [antiques] business as long as I’ve been, which is some 30 odd years almost, there are some things I’ve never seen before – and that really cracks me up,” he said.

A closet full of colorful jackets.
The colorful TV appraiser dresses fittingly so.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

Alison Kenworthy, 38, an Emmy-winning television producer who previously worked for “Good Morning America” — and who’s the founder and executive producer of Homeworthy — saw Lowry as a perfect fit for the old world-style apartment he calls home.

“The guy wears three-piece suits and a handlebar mustache — and described his home as a ‘bohemian hangout or post-apocalyptic garage sale … smorgasbord of everything,’ ” she said. “He is just an eccentric and interesting charismatic individual, and his apartment is a perfect reflection of that.”

Nicholas Lowry and his dog inside is self-described “wunderkammer” of a home.
Bless this mess: Nicholas Lowry and his dog inside is his self-described “wunderkammer” of a home.
Alison Kenworthy/Homeworthy

“I’m someone who suffers from ‘clutter-itis,’ ” Lowry said in the video – but does that mean he’s done collecting? No, he said – he’ll keep filling the space as much as he can. Even now, he’s on the hunt for a reproduction Egyptian-style sarcophagus to use as décor.

“I hear from countless people, ‘You don’t have room for anything else!’ ” he said. “There’s always room for something else.”

https://nypost.com/2021/12/22/inside-antiques-roadshow-host-nicholas-lowrys-nyc-home/